mankiw

更新时间:2023-06-20 19:45:58 阅读: 评论:0

Mankiw’s Ten Principles of Economics, Translated for the Uninitiated参与者
by Yoram Bauman1 (revid June 12, 2002) The cornerstone of Harvard professor N. Gregory Mankiw’s introductory economics textbook, Principles of Economics, is a synthesis of economic thought into Ten Principles of Economics (listed in the first table below). A quick perusal of the will likely affirm the reader’s suspicions that synthesizing economic thought into Ten Principles is no easy task, and may even lead the reader to suspect that the subtlety and concision required are not to be found in the pen of N. Gregory Mankiw.
I have taken it upon mylf to remedy this unfortunate situation. The cond table below summarizes my attempt to translate Mankiw’s Ten Principles into plain English, and in doing so to provide the uninitiated with an invaluable glimp of the economic mind at work. Explanations and details can be found in the pages that follow, but the average reader is advid to simply cut out the table below and carry it around for assistance in the (hereafter unlikely) event of confusion about the basic Principles of Economics.
Mankiw’s Principles
#1 People face tradeoffs
#2 The cost of something is what you give up to get it
#3 Rational people think at the margin
#4 People respond to incentivessucceeded
licen#5 Trade can make everyone better off
#6 Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity
#7 Governments can sometimes improve market outcomes
tenderness是什么意思
#8    A country’s standard of living depends on its ability to produce goods and rvices #9 Prices ri when the government prints too much money
#10 Society faces a short-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment
Yoram’s Translations
#1 Choices are bad
#2 Choices are really bad
#3 People are stupid
#4 People aren’t that stupid
#5 Trade can make everyone wor off
#6 Governments are stupid
#7 Governments aren’t that stupid
#8 Blah blah blah
#9 Blah blah blah
#10 Blah blah blah
1 I welcome comments—humorous or otherwi—about this or about my own microeconomics text, Quantum Microeconomics, which can be found online at students.washington.edu/yoram)
Explanations and Details
At first glance, the reader cannot but be impresd by the translation’s simplicity and clarity. Accessibility, however, should not be mistaken for shallowness: further study will reveal hidden depths and subtleties that will richly reward the attentive student. Indeed, a moment’s reflection will identify any number of puzzles and mysteries. Chief among them is probably this: Why do Principles #8, #9, and #10 have identical translations?
The immediately obvious explanation is that the are macro-economic principles, and that I, as a micro-economist, am ill equipped to understand them, let alone translate them.2 As is often the ca in this complex world we live in, this immediately obvious explanation is also wrong. The true reason I have provided identical translations of “Blah blah blah” for Principles #8, #9, and #10 is that the principles say exactly the same thing, namely, “Blah blah blah.” Sometime when you've got a few hours to spare, go and ask an economist—preferably a macro-economist—what he or she really means by “standard of living” or “goods and rvices” or “inflation” or “unemployment” or “short-run” or even “too much.” You will soon realize that there is a vast difference between, say, what Principle #10 says—“Society faces a short-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment”—and what Principle #10 means:“Society faces blah between blah and blah.” My translations are simply conci renderings of the underlying meanings.
Having cleared up that issue, let us go back to Mankiw’s
Principle #1: People face tradeoffs
Translation: Choices are bad
The reasoning behind this translation is obvious. For example, imagine that somebody comes up to you and offers you a choice between a Snickers bar and some M&Ms. You now have a tradeoff, meaning that you have to choo one or the other. And having to trade one thing off against another is bad; President Truman suppodly asked for a one-armed economics advisor becau his two-armed economics advisors were always saying, “On the but on the ”
People who have not received any economics education might be tempted to think that choices are good. They aren't. The (mistaken) idea that choices are good perhaps stems from the (equally mistaken) idea that lack of choices is bad. This is simply not true, as Mancur Olson points out in his book, The Logic of Collective Action:“To say a situation is ‘lost’ or hopeless is in one n equivalent to saying it is perfect, for in both cas efforts at improvement can bring no positive results.”
Hence my translation of Mankiw's first principle of economics: Choices are bad. This concept can be a little difficult to grasp—nobody ever said economics was easy—but the troubled reader will undoubtedly gain clarity from Mankiw's
2 The exact meanings of the terms “micro” and “macro” may be lost on the reader—or, more likely, may never have been found in the first place. This should not be cau for concern: abnce of the terms from Mankiw’s Ten Principles indicates that they are not of fundamental economic importance.
Principle #2: The cost of something is what you give up to get it
Translation: Choices are really bad
Beyond transforming Mankiw’s mantic deathtrap into simplicity itlf, this translation has the advantage of establishing a connection between Principle #1 (Choices are bad) and Principle #2 (Choices are really bad).
To continue to deepen the reader’s understanding of why choices are bad—really bad—let's return to our previous example, in which somebody offers you a choice between a Snickers bar and a pack
脑死age of M&Ms. Suppo, for the sake of argument, that you take the M&Ms. According to Mankiw, the cost of tho M&Ms is the Snickers bar that you had to give up to get the M&Ms. Your gain from this situation—what economists call “economic profit”—is therefore the difference between the value you gain from getting the M&Ms (say, $.75) and the value you lo from giving up the Snickers bar (say, $.40). In other words, your economic profit is only $.35. Although you value the M&Ms at $.75, having the choice of the Snickers bar reduces your gain by $.40. Hence Principle #2: Choices are really bad.
Indeed, the more choices you have, the wor off you are. The worst situation of all would be somebody coming up to you and offering you a choice between two identical packages of M&Ms. Since choosing one package (which you value at $.75) means giving up the other package (which you also value at $.75), your economic profit is exactly zero! So being offered a choice between two identical packages of M&Ms is in fact equivalent to being offered nothing.
Now, a lay person might be forgiven for thinking that being offered a choice between two identical packages of M&Ms is in fact equivalent to being offered a single package of M&Ms. But economists know better. Being offered a single package of M&M effectively means having to choo between a package of M&Ms (which you value at $.75) and nothing (which you value at $0). Choosing the M&M
s gives you an economic profit of $.75, which is $.75 more than your economic profit when you are offered a choice between two identical packages of M&Ms.
At this point it is worth acknowledging that (1) there may be readers who have failed to grasp the above subtleties in their entirety, and (2) such readers may well be beginning to wonder whether they are, in a word, stupid. Any lingering doubts should be eliminated by the Mankiw's
Principle #3: Rational people think at the margin
Translation: People are stupid
One point that is immediately obvious to the most casual obrver with the meanest intelligence is that most people do not think at the margin. For example, most people who buy oranges at the grocery store think like this: “Hmmm, oranges are $.25 each. I think I'll buy half a dozen.” They do not think like this: “Hmmm, oranges are $.25 each. I'm going to buy one, becau my marginal value exceeds the market price. Now I'm going to buy a cond one, becau my marginal value still exceeds the ” We know
most people don't think like this becau most people don't fill their shopping baskets one orange at a time!
But we are now led inexorably toward a most unhappy conclusion. If—as Mankiw says—rational people think at the margin, and if—as we all know—most people do not think at the margin, then most people are not rational. Most people, in other words, are stupid. Hence my translation of the third principle of economics: People are stupid.
Before sinking into despair for the fate of the human race, however, the reader would be wi to consider Mankiw's
Principle #4: People respond to incentives.
Translation: People aren’t that stupid.
same是什么意思The dictionary says that incentive, n., is 1. Something that influences to action; stimulus; encouragement. SYN. e motive.
So what Mankiw is saying here is that people are motivated by motives, or that people are influenced to action by things that influence to action. Now, this may em to be a bit like saying that tautologies are tautological—the reader may be thinking that people would have to be pretty stupid to be unmotivated by motives, or to be inactive in respon to something that influences to action. B
ut remember Principle #3: People are stupid. Hence the need for Principle #4, to clarify that people aren’t that stupid.
Only truly stupid people can fail to understand my translation of Mankiw's Principle #5: Trade can make everyone better off
Translation: Trade can make everyone wor off
But, the reader may well be asking, isn't the translation of the fifth principle the exact opposite of the principle itlf? Of cour not.
雅思论坛To e why, first note that "trade can make everyone better off" is patently obviously: if I have a Snickers bar and want M&Ms and you have M&Ms and want a Snickers bar, we can trade and we will both be better off. Surely Mankiw is getting at something deeper than this? Indeed, I believe he is. To e what it is, compare the following phras:
A: Trade can make everyone better off
k歌情人插曲B: Trade will make everyone better off
Now, Statement B is clearly superior to Statement A. Why, then, does Mankiw u Statement A? It can only be becau Statement B is fal. By saying that trade can make everyone better off, Mankiw is conveying one of the subtleties of economics: trade can
also not make everyone better off. It is a short hop from here to my translation, “Trade can make everybody wor off.” (A numerical example can be found in this footnote.3) The subtlety evident in Principle #5 is even more clearly visible in the next two principles.
Principle #6: Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Translation: Governments are stupid.
上海福山外国语小学
Principle #7: Governments can sometimes improve market outcomes Translation: Governments aren’t that stupid.
To e the key role that Principle #5 plays in both of the statements, note that the original phrasing of Principle #5 (“Trade can make everyone better off”) leads to Principle #6 (“Governments are stupid”). After all, if trade can make everyone better off, what do we need government for? But the translation of Principle #5 (“Trade can make everyone wor off”) leads to Principle #7 (“Governments aren’t that stupid”). After all, if trade can make everyone wor off, we better have a
government around to stop people from trading!
Like the first five principles, Principles #6 and #7 demonstrate the fine distinctions inherent in the economic way of thinking. People are stupid, but not that stupid; trade can make everyone better off, but it can also make everyone wor off; governments are stupid, but not that stupid. Exploring, refining, and delineating the distinctions is the subject matter of upper-level economics class, doctoral disrtations in economics, and the vast majority of papers in the American Economic Review and other scholarly journals. Should the reader decide to follow this path, the fundamental principles described on the first page of this article will provide invaluable guidance.
3 Consider a small town with three families. It just so happens that Family #1 needs a snowblower, Family #2 needs a leafblower, and Family #3 needs a lawnmower; each family values their particular need at $200. Fortune appears to be smiling on this town, becau it also just so happens that Family #1 owns a leafblower, Family #2 owns a lawnmower, and Family #3 owns a snowblower. The sit unud in their respective garages; each family has no u for its current piece of equipment, and therefore values it at $0.
The situation appears ripe for gains from trade: Family #1 could buy a snowblower from Family #3 fo
r $100, Family #2 could buy a leafblower from Family #1 for $100, and Family #3 could buy a lawnmower from Family #2 for $100. Each family would be $200 better off.
Unfortunately, life in this small town is not so simple; the town is located in a valley that is susceptible to vere air pollution problems. Blowers and mowers emit large quantities of air pollutants, and in fact each blower or mower that is ud will make air pollution so bad that hospital bills (for asthma &etc) will increa by $80 for each family. Three additional blowers and mowers will therefore increa each family’s bills by $240.
Two results follow. First, the trades will still take place. For example, Family #1 and Family #3 will both be better off by $100 - $80 = $20 if Family #3 lls Family #1 its snowblower for $100. Second, the three trades together make everyone wor off: each family gains $200 from buying and lling, but los $240 in hospital bills, for a net loss of $40.veritas

本文发布于:2023-06-20 19:45:58,感谢您对本站的认可!

本文链接:https://www.wtabcd.cn/fanwen/fan/78/1000580.html

版权声明:本站内容均来自互联网,仅供演示用,请勿用于商业和其他非法用途。如果侵犯了您的权益请与我们联系,我们将在24小时内删除。

标签:福山   插曲   小学   情人   上海
相关文章
留言与评论(共有 0 条评论)
   
验证码:
推荐文章
排行榜
Copyright ©2019-2022 Comsenz Inc.Powered by © 专利检索| 网站地图